Keep up-to-date with drugs and crime

The latest research, policy, practice and opinion on our criminal justice and drug & alcohol treatment systems
Search

Can payment by results transfer risk?

It is not possible to transfer all risk, be that risk reputational, practical or financial. Commissioners retain their responsibility for local citizens receiving a good quality and effective service.

Share This Post

 PbR and risk

This is the sixth post in a blog series looking at the lessons I’ve learned from a recent review of the payment by results literature. One of the reasons that commissioners are attracted to the concept of PbR is the way in which PbR schemes allow commissioners to transfer practical and financial risk to providers; by linking payment to defined results, commissioners ensure they do not pay for poor performance.

The provider (or, in the case of Social Impact Bonds, a third party investor) is often expected to cover early start-up and running costs until payments for success reimburse this outlay. This transfers the financial risk of setting up a new scheme from the commissioner to the provider. The use of social investment (both the Peterborough prisoner resettlement and the London rough sleepers PbR pilots were funded by Social Impact Bonds) allows commissioners to invest in new approaches without needing to find new money from budgets already under pressure.

But can PbR schemes really transfer risk?

[button-blue url=”https://www.russellwebster.com/Lessons%20from%20the%20Payment%20by%20Results%20literature%20Russell%20Webster%202016.pdf” target=”_self” position=”left”]You can download the full literature review here[/button-blue]

 [divider]

Transferring risk is not straightforward

However, the Audit Commission, in the first thorough UK examination of PbR,  emphasised that it is not possible to transfer all risk, be that risk reputational, practical or financial. Commissioners retain their responsibility for local citizens receiving a good quality and effective service. They must also be diligent in ensuring that the terms of a PbR contracts are not too generous so that the public continues to receive good value for money.

Certainly politicians have made much of the advantages of payment by results transferring risk to providers, enabling them to argue that new government PbR initiatives will ensure proper value for public money. Chris Grayling, the government minister responsible for both the Work Programme (as Minister of State for Employment) and the Transforming Rehabilitation new probation contracts (as Justice Secretary) argued consistently that one of the core advantages of PbR is that new providers would not be paid in the case of poor performance.

Risk tightrope

Yardstick competition

Perhaps the best example of how risk can be transferred is the Work Programme which compares the performance of 18 prime contractors operating 40 contracts in 18 contract package areas (CPAs) – there are two to three contracts in every CPA. This “yardstick competition” allows providers to be more fairly judged and commissioners to reward successful providers by allocating them a greater share of the contract. In the case of the Work Programme, the DWP regularly reviews performance and shifts market share as a result; for instance, in August 2013 substantial components of the contracts in 10 of the 18 CPAs were transferred from poorly performing providers to companies achieving better outcomes.

Clist & Dercon developed 12 principles for payment by results in international development in which they argue that risk transfer is not a rationale for PbR per se; stating that the primary purpose of transferring risk should be to sharpen performance incentives for the provider, and not for the commissioner to offload risk.

[Clist, P. & Dercon, S. (2014) 12 principles for payment by results in international development. London: Department for International Development.]

Conclusion

The National Audit Office cautions that although PbR transfers some risk to providers, commissioners need to be aware of the risks they retain, in particular overall responsibility for a public service, and recommends that, wherever possible, commissioners pilot new PbR schemes.

 

Having looked at some of the key reasons for commissioning via PbR, the next few Wednesdays will turn attention to what the literature tells us about what makes PbR schemes succeed — and fail — starting with the importance of understanding a market before deciding whether to use payment by results.

I reviewed the literature as part of a project funded by the Oak Foundation to develop an interactive tool to assist commissioners and providers to decide whether a payment by results approach might be an effective approach to commissioning a particular service.

The tool is now live – please check it out at: www.PbR.russellwebster.com

Share This Post

Related posts

On Probation
11/21 private probation companies hit PbR targets

There have been statistically significant reductions in the adjusted binary reoffending rate for 11 of the 21 CRCs in the April to June 2016 cohort when compared to the 2011 baseline reoffending rates.

Infographics
PbR jargon demystified (3) M-R

Third in a series of infographics which demystify the jargon and technical terms associated with the payment by results commissioning model.

Payment by Results
What we know about payment by results

This final post summarises the most important lessons to bear in mind if you are involved in commissioning, investing in or providing a payment by results-funded scheme.

Featured
The unexpected consequences of payment by results

The issue of providers “gaming” PbR contracts is a hot issue in the literature. Commentators take different views with some stating that it is only rational and efficient for providers to focus on the outcomes incentivised by PbR payments to the best of their ability while others describe similar behaviour as “gaming.”

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Subscribe

Get every blog post by email for free